2021年5月7日 星期五

On Tech: Computer chips are the new toilet paper

Really.

Computer chips are the new toilet paper

Robert Beatty

Most people need toilet paper and computer chips every day, and yet we rarely think about either of them.

That changed during the coronavirus pandemic when first bathroom rolls and then chips became scarce. Computer chips aren't so disposable, but they are equally essential as electronic brains for products like smartphones, cars, airplanes and most modern appliances. Chip shortages have stalled new car manufacturing, made rental cars harder to find and complicated business even for the dog washing industry.

I spoke to Don Clark, who has written about computer chips for years, about the importance of chips, why the U.S. government is obsessed with making more of them in America, and how a new chip mania is a revenge for the nerds.

Shira: What are computer chips used for?

Don: Computer chips are like tiny brains or memory receptacles. This makes them important for pretty much everything in modern life. The obvious places are electronics like computers, smartphones, video game consoles and voice-activated speakers.

But chips are also in products that are used to track milk production of dairy cows and to make sure produce in trucks stays at an appropriate temperature. A modern car can have several thousand chips, including for the ignition, brakes and entertainment system. This year, the production of $50,000 cars is being held up because of a lack of $1 computer chips.

Right, how did chips lead to a freeze in car manufacturing?

Last year, when the pandemic first hit, automakers estimated that many people wouldn't want to buy cars, and they cut orders for computer chips. When it turned out that car sales increased, the companies tried to order more chips on the fly. But the chip manufacturers had already moved on. They had shifted production to fill orders for products like phones and game consoles.

Are chip shortages unusual?

No, but shortages are usually confined to one particular type of chip. What's unusual about this year is there's not enough of many different kinds of computer chips, because of a combination of some disruptions related to the pandemic and overwhelming demand for more and more chips for everything.

ADVERTISEMENT

To give just one example, each new smartphone with a 5G internet connection has 100 little components in it called filters that connect to all the different frequencies. That's 100 computer chips for just a single function.

When will the shortages improve?

Companies are trying to crank out more chips, but it's difficult to react quickly. Chip companies are also trying to stop customers, including car companies, from ordering double the number of chips they really need just to be sure they get some. But shortages will probably last until 2022 and could get worse before they get better. That's partly because many scarce chips come from older factories that are hard to upgrade.

Congress and President Biden seem very likely to back billions of taxpayer dollars to make more computer chips in the United States. Why?

ADVERTISEMENT

Shortages of products like personal protective equipment made in China have gotten the public and policymakers to discuss the downsides of having essential products made outside the United States.

Many advanced computer chips are made in Taiwan, and that makes the Pentagon in particular nervous about not being able to get essential computer chips if relations between Taiwan and China get worse. And the U.S. government wants to be more self reliant in the case of emergencies, like earthquakes, in Taiwan.

Another issue is global competitiveness. Countries including Ireland, Taiwan and Israel give boatloads of government incentives to factories that produce chips. Intel, the big American computer chip company, doesn't really need U.S. taxpayers' money. But it wants to ensure that the company isn't doing vastly worse by making its chips in the United States.

Forgive me, but the computer chip industry is very nerdy. How do people in the industry feel about being such a hot topic?

ADVERTISEMENT

Yes, this has been the boring old industry of tech, like steel making. That's changing, partly because of the attention on chip shortages but that's not the only reason.

I wrote an article on Friday about the amount of investments in new computer chip companies — about eight times the dollars invested in 2016. Young people who might have formed software start-ups a few years ago are now choosing to start chip companies. There is a lot of interest and excitement in chips now, and the people in the industry feel that it's nice to be seen as really important.

If you don't already get this newsletter in your inbox, please sign up here.

SUBSCRIBE TODAY

If you've found this newsletter helpful, please consider subscribing to The New York Times — with this special offer. Your support makes our work possible.

Before we go …

  • Not a great look for internet service providers: An analysis by the New York attorney general found that internet providers including AT&T and Comcast funded an effort that yielded millions of fake comments opposing net neutrality rules, my colleague David McCabe wrote. And from February: An explanation of net neutrality and the long war over it.
  • Also not great: The Markup reported that pharmaceutical companies find potential patients on Facebook by using drug ads to target people based on their interests in topics like bourbon or oxygen or their involvement in a depression and bipolar support group.
  • Yes, better online safety for all! Google said that it would start requiring people to take an added security measure, such as responding to a smartphone notification, to sign into Gmail and other accounts. It's great that Google is making this the default; here's why adding a verification to log into our digital accounts is the most important thing we can do to protect our security.

Hugs to this

The saga of red-tailed hawks named Billy and Lilly, and babies Alba and Eli, "is one of regeneration and joy, with a tinge of sadness and some dead rat carcasses."

We want to hear from you. Tell us what you think of this newsletter and what else you'd like us to explore. You can reach us at ontech@nytimes.com.

If you don't already get this newsletter in your inbox, please sign up here. You can also read past On Tech columns.

Need help? Review our newsletter help page or contact us for assistance.

You received this email because you signed up for On Tech with Shira Ovide from The New York Times.

To stop receiving these emails, unsubscribe or manage your email preferences.

Subscribe to The Times

Connect with us on:

facebooktwitterinstagram

Change Your EmailPrivacy PolicyContact UsCalifornia Notices

LiveIntent LogoAdChoices Logo

The New York Times Company. 620 Eighth Avenue New York, NY 10018

歡迎蒞臨:https://ofa588.com/

娛樂推薦:https://www.ofa86.com/

Wonking Out: Braking Bad?

If you don't think Janet Yellen was right, ask yourself why.
Author Headshot

By Paul Krugman

Opinion Columnist

Alert! Wonk warning! This is an additional email that goes deeper into the economics and some technical stuff than usual.

I began today's column with Janet Yellen's totally reasonable yet PR-problematic remark that the Fed might respond to an overheating economy by moderately raising interest rates. One question I didn't get into but seems worth asking is: who disagrees with that proposition, and why? And asking that question seems to me to lead into some more meta issues about when you should — or shouldn't — base policy arguments on novel economic ideas.

Let's start with the economic model that, I believe, underlies a lot of the macroeconomic discussion you hear; it certainly underlies much of what I write about fiscal and monetary policy. The basic idea is simple: other things equal, the economy will be stronger the lower the interest rate set by the Fed:

The workhorse macro model.Author

(Why IS? Tradition. It stands for "investment-savings," and it's not worth going into why right now.)

The usual caveats apply. Aggregate demand doesn't respond instantly to monetary policy, so this is a schematic, static representation of something that actually has hard-to-predict dynamics. We don't have really good estimates of the IS curve's slope or of the economy's maximum sustainable potential either, so if you ask, "how much would rates need to fall to achieve maximum employment" all we can provide is a modestly educated guess.

ADVERTISEMENT

Still, this is enough of a framework to understand the issue that has bedeviled economic policy for much of the past 15 years. The Fed can fight a slump by cutting rates, but there's a limit to how low it can go — the "zero lower bound," even if it's not exactly zero. If that, for whatever reason, turns out not to be low enough, we're in a liquidity trap, and we need fiscal stimulus that pushes the IS curve to the right to achieve full employment.

This was the logic behind the 2009 Obama stimulus. Unfortunately that stimulus was too small to close the output gap. (That's not hindsight, I was screaming about it at the time.) This time, however, the American Rescue Plan, although not designed primarily as stimulus, is truly huge, and will probably deliver more than enough stimulus to close the gap and then some.

But will this lead to inflation? Way back in 2009 some of us argued, in vain, that there was much less risk in going too big than in going too small, because if the stimulus turned out to be bigger than needed the Fed could always tap the brakes:

Yellen's point.Author

And that's exactly what Yellen was saying. So who disagrees, and why?

ADVERTISEMENT

SUBSCRIBE TODAY

New York Times Opinion highlights a range of perspectives and voices. This work is made possible with the support of subscribers. Please consider supporting The Times with this special offer.

Well, if you don't believe that monetary and fiscal policy are potentially independent policy instruments — which is what I think the Modern Monetary Theory people are saying, although it's always hard to pin them down — then you don't believe the Fed can put the brakes on if the stimulus is more than needed. Notice, by the way, that in this case MMT, if taken seriously, should make you less willing to go big with progressive fiscal policies than if you were a conventional Keynesian: Janet Yellen and I believe that the Fed can contain any inflationary risks, but MMTers, as far as I can tell, don't.

A more explicit critique comes from Larry Summers, who has warned that the stimulus may lead to stagflation. He appears to believe that the Fed can't use monetary tightening to offset overheating generated by fiscal expansion without causing a nasty recession. But I have to admit to being a bit puzzled about why. As far as I know — and Summers and I have known each other and been professional colleagues for 40 years — his underlying macroeconomic model is pretty much the same as mine, and the same as the one illustrated in the figures above. And that model seems to say that the Fed can indeed tap on the brakes if needed.

Indeed, the Fed has done that in the past: in the 80s and again in the 90s it acted to rein in booms without causing recessions:

ADVERTISEMENT

Braking without sending the economy into a skid. FRED

What I think he's doing is assuming that the Fed will wait too long, allowing inflation to get embedded in the economy before it tightens. That could indeed be a problem — but isn't that an argument for the Fed to be alert, rather than a reason to believe that it's hugely dangerous to enact a stimulus that might be bigger than necessary?

In general, claims that we can't rely on the Fed to rein in inflation if the stimulus turns out to be too big have to rest on some departure from the workhorse model most sensible people use to think about macroeconomic policy. Should you do that?

Obviously no model is sacred, and questioning conventional wisdom is something you should always be doing. But there is a danger in coming up with novel economic doctrines on the fly, especially when you're using those novel doctrines to justify your political views. Are you really engaging in critical analysis, or are you simply engaging in motivated reasoning?

I speak, by the way, from personal experience. On election night 2016, I let my (totally justified) dismay over the results warp my economic judgment, making a recession call that didn't flow from my own models. I retracted with a mea culpa three days later. What the episode reminded me was that new thinking should be done with a cool head, and you should be extra careful when it leads to conclusions you want to hear.

I should have known better (and did, after three days) after the history of economics in the aftermath of the Great Recession. When financial crisis struck, there were many calls for new economic thinking, but standard analysis actually did a pretty good job once economists realized that the rise of shadow banking had resurrected old-fashioned bank runs in a new guise.

Yet there was a considerable amount of influential new thinking — not on behalf of effective policies to restore full employment, but to justify austerity policies in the face of mass unemployment. In particular, there were unconventional analyses suggesting that debt in excess of 90 percent of G.D.P. would somehow have devastating effects on economic growth and that fiscal contraction would somehow be expansionary, because it would improve confidence. These novel ideas were enthusiastically adopted by many politicians and policymakers. They also turned out to be completely wrong.

So even if you're uncomfortable with President Biden's fiscal policies, you should be very cautious about making arguments against them that rely on novel propositions about why inflation can't be contained. Conventional analysis says what Janet Yellen said: If the stimulus proves bigger than needed, the Fed can keep things under control. If you're asserting otherwise, think hard about why you're saying that.

Feedback
If you're enjoying what you're reading, please consider recommending it to friends. They can sign up here. If you want to share your thoughts on an item in this week's newsletter or on the newsletter in general, please email me at krugman-newsletter@nytimes.com.

Need help? Review our newsletter help page or contact us for assistance.

You received this email because you signed up for Paul Krugman from The New York Times.

To stop receiving these emails, unsubscribe or manage your email preferences.

Subscribe to The Times

Connect with us on:

facebooktwitterinstagram

Change Your EmailPrivacy PolicyContact UsCalifornia Notices

LiveIntent LogoAdChoices Logo

The New York Times Company. 620 Eighth Avenue New York, NY 10018

歡迎蒞臨:https://ofa588.com/

娛樂推薦:https://www.ofa86.com/